Henry Kaspar:
My Discomfort with Quasi-Monetarism
Regular readers of the blog will be familiar with the term"quasi-monetarists": a group of economists that includes Nick Rowe, Scott Sumner or David Beckworth ...is trying to push the following, powerful message (with
differing emphasis on the specific elements, depending on the author):
1. The cause of the crisis is excess
demand for money (=money hoarding). Excess demand for money implies
necessarily insufficient demand for goods (with sticky prices).
2. The way out of the crisis is a
monetary policy that brings supply and demand for money back into
equilibrium, and thus ends the hoarding of money.
...
Now here is how I see things:
1b. Excess indebtedness forces debtors
to reduce expenditures in order to be able to service their debts –
i.e., it forces a transfer from debtors to creditors. The creditors’
propensity to spend is lower than that of debtors; after all this is why
they are creditors. They would want to lend on the means transferred to
them, but do not find enough households or firms willing and able to
take on more debt. To use Brad DeLong’s term: there is a lack of safe assets.
1c. Because of the lack of safe assets creditors hoard money.
It is important to note that I agree with the quasi-monetarists on
two points: (i) the problem is insufficient aggregate demand, and (ii)
by logical necessity, the counterpart to insufficient demand for goods
is money hoarding. But money hoarding is a symptom of the crisis, not its cause. Put differently, causality goes from lack of aggregate demand to money hoarding, not the other way round.
Nick Rowe ...often employs a nice thought experiment
that describes the above identity more graphically – but can easily
mislead if sloppily given a causal or even economic policy
interpretation: suppose there was no money, and therefore also no
possibility to hoard money - then there could be no lack of aggregate
demand for goods. Does this not suggest that policy makers should focus
on ending money hoarding? And aren’t things related to money the task of
the central bank, i.e., isn’t monetary policy responsible here?
It does not – as there are more promising options to combat
insufficient demand and (therefore) money hoarding (see below). This is
the source of my discomfort with quasi-monetarism: a tendency to cut
down the characterization of the crisis to the one aspect that
helps pushing their (monetary) policy point. And this is important, as they way we present problems affects how we think about their solution.
My characterization suggests the following policy options:
2a. Debt relief.
Debt relief reduces the debt payment burden and thus allows debtors to
spend more of their income on goods. Hence, in the U.S., for example,
schemes are needed that strengthen incentives for lenders to write down mortgage loans. And in Europe some debts of the most overindebted countries need to be cancelled.
2b. Government indebtedness, i.e. expansionary fiscal policy. If the private sector is incapable of absorbing all desired savings the government has to jump in
– at least temporarily, while the private sector is paying down its
excess debts. The government offers savers a safe asset (government
bonds) and uses the funds to directly boost aggregate demand. This,
however, is only an option when the government is not overindebted
itself (as is the case in some GIPS-countries).
2c. Monetary policy comes at best in third place, as it
is worst in addressing the crisis’ underlying cause. Monetary policy
can stimulate aggregate demand only if it incentivizes the private
sector to indebt itself. But the private sector is already overindebted,
to a point where even nominal interest rates of zero or close to
zero fail to generate enough willingness to take on debt. And, as is
well known, at the zero bound monetary policy encounters some difficulties.
In one sentence: lack of demand and (therefore) money hoarding are there only because of
insufficient efforts to (i) reduce the private sector’s debt burden,
and to (ii) compensate for the loss in demand from the overindebted
private sector by sufficiently increasing demand from the public sector.
If so, policy makers should focus on promoting debt relief
and boosting public sector demand, instead of placing all the burden on
an instrument – monetary policy – that has hit a constraint.
I would add that monetary policy could produce inflation which would be a good thing for a "balance-sheet recession" because it would reduce the real debt burden for most people. Much debt has a fixed interest rate. Higher inflation reduces the real value of the debt and lightens balance sheets.
Krugman added a few more comments on the above post:
So:
an overall shortfall of demand, in which people just don’t want to buy
enough goods to maintain full employment, can only happen in a monetary
economy; it’s correct to say that what’s happening in such a situation
is that people are trying to hoard money instead (which is the moral of
the story of the
baby-sitting coop). And this problem can ordinarily be solved by simply providing more money.
But
we’re not in an ordinary situation here, we’re in a liquidity trap in
which short-term interest rates have been driven to zero, yet the
economy still languishes.
What
that means is that when people are hoarding money, they’re no longer
doing so because of its moneyness — the liquidity it provides, which
makes money different from other assets. They’ve already got all the
liquidity they want, since liquidity is free — you don’t have to
sacrifice interest earnings to get more, so people are saturated. So at
the margin, they’re holding money simply as a store of value.
Now,
what monetary policy ordinarily involves is open-market operations: the
central bank increases the supply of money by purchasing and removing
from the market non-money assets. And this has traction because money is
different from these other assets. In a liquidity trap, however, money isn’t different: at the margin an open-market operation just exchanges one store of value for another, with no economic effect.
So this is a situation in which the economic problems cannot be solved just by increasing the supply of money.
Now,
in principle you can get traction by making money a less attractive
store of value. In particular, if you can credibly promise future
inflation, that will make the real return on money negative. But getting
that kind of credibility is tricky, especially given the normal
prejudices of central bankers. And in any case it’s very different from
the kind of thinking we normally associate with monetarism, which
focuses on the current money supply.
Nor does focusing on nominal GDP instead of M2 or whatever really bridge the gap. The
point about M2-based monetarism was that it was supposed to give the
Fed a target it could clearly control — although in a liquidity trap it
turns out that even that isn’t true. Whatever else it is, and whatever virtues it may have, nominal GDP isn’t that kind of target.
No comments:
Post a Comment